91传媒

Skip to main content

What are tariffs, who pays for them and what can they do to the economy?

What are tariffs, who pays for them and what can they do to the economy?

President Donald Trump may institute blanket tariffs on Wednesday, April 2鈥攖he latest development in an ongoing tariff and economic strategy that has created uncertainty around the world.听

Since taking office, Trump has threatened, rescinded and in some cases, implemented tariffs on several of the United States' largest trading partners, including China, Mexico and Canada.听

Keith Maskus is a professor emeritus in economics at the University of Colorado Boulder and served as Chief Economist at the U.S. Department of State in 2016 and 2017. He sat down with 91传媒 Today to explain the history of tariffs and give his take on what it means for the economy and the average consumer.听

In its most basic form, what is a tariff?

A tariff is an import tax. It is literally a tax on imports; not on the domestic production of goods that compete with imports. In that sense, it is a discriminatory tax. It's also a tax on consumption because imports make up a pretty large share of U.S. goods that are consumed and also of the inputs that are used in production in the United States.

For example, imagine you bring in a television, it鈥檚 coming from China, and the export price for the TV is $400 with a 10% tariff. When that product lands in the United States, it sits in a warehouse until somebody pays the government $40. The importer鈥擶almart, Target or somebody else鈥攈as to pay that $40. Then they have to decide whether they're going to mark that $40 up into a higher sales price for consumers, which they almost always do within a matter of 6-8 months. So, it鈥檚 simply false to believe or argue that exporters will pay the cost of these tariffs. Domestic consumers and businesses pay them.

How have tariffs historically been used in the United States?

A photo of a white man looking directly at the camera, wearing a blue suit, white shirt and red tie.

Professor Emeritus Keith Maskus.听

Early in its history the United States was an agricultural economy and there was not much industry. With industrialization in the late 19th century, tariffs were still important for protection and raising government revenue, but were coming down because it was significant for industrialists to have access to international components and labor. In 1913, the United States replaced tariffs and some other forms of revenue with the income tax and almost immediately, tariffs became unimportant as a matter of revenue generation.

Tariffs came back with the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930, when the U.S., concerned about an oncoming reduction in employment and what seemed to be a recession at the time, raised the average tariff rate on affected imports to well over 50%. All of the other major countries in the world retaliated very quickly at that time, and global trade from 1930 to 1932 was cut by 70%, both due to the tariff increases and to declining incomes. That tariff war was a real contributing factor to the Great Depression.

From the 1950s through the 1990s, there was a generalized reduction in global tariff rates imposed on manufactured goods and consumer goods. The United States has been a very open economy in this context. So have Europe, Canada and other similar countries. And that opening was pretty much led by the United States, and later, the United States and Europe together. President Trump is fond of saying that the world is screwing the United States through its trade policy. But in fact, the history here is that the Americans led this process toward pretty free global trade, and we benefited as much as anyone else from it, through access to lower prices and international technologies and investment.

How is that different from what we鈥檙e seeing in headlines now?

The trade war initiated by the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act in 1930 was massive, but it did not have this kind of strange variability from day to day鈥攖he varying tariff rates and threats to use tariffs for things they don鈥檛 really work for. At that time, countries raised their tariffs and kept them at those high levels for a good seven, eight years.

Now, trade wars of this kind are exceptionally uncommon, and the only one of any consequence after World War II was between the first Trump administration and China. You may recall that we put in these high tariffs on steel and aluminum from many countries, including China, and they responded. Then we put higher tariffs on a lot of their imports. They responded, and so on.

The current Trump administration, as far as I can tell, has not articulated exactly what they're trying to achieve with all of this variability and these threats. It generates considerable economic uncertainty, and of course, also generates a feeling, on behalf of our trading partners, that the United States is becoming untrustworthy and can't really be depended on to lead the global economy the way we've been doing for generations.

What are some examples of 鈥漸sing tariffs for things they don鈥檛 really work for?鈥

Two men, Justin Trudeau and Donald Trump, sitting on chairs in front of Canadian and American flags.

President Donald Trump with Canadian Prime Minister Justin Trudeau in 2019. (Credit: Wikimedia Commons/State Department Photo)

Tariffs are primarily used to protect domestic industry from import competition. That was easier in the 19th and middle of the 20th century鈥攏ow international supply chains are much more complicated, making tariffs a significant element of costs of production around the world.

Tariffs can also be used to raise revenue. But they鈥檙e really only used that way in developing countries. In the U.S., Canada, Europe and other rich countries, that strategy has long since been replaced by more efficient and broader tax systems, such as the income tax here or the value added tax elsewhere.

More recently, we're seeing tariffs used as components of sanctions packages. So as you know, we have very extensive economic sanctions against Iran and North Korea, Russia, and several other countries, including China. The sanctions exist in principle to try to change behavior that we don't like. Sanctions do economic damage to those countries, but they don't change the government's behavior very much.

In this new environment, we see one person deciding tariffs are appropriate tools to use to achieve or influence almost anything, like pressuring Canada and Mexico to up their immigration enforcement and stop the flow of fentanyl into the United States.听

Let鈥檚 use fentanyl as a detailed example:

If you really want to deal with the fentanyl problem in the United States, it's really an American problem. We have this excessive demand for illicit drugs. And if you want to deal with that, you need to come up with interventions that try to work at the source. Even if tariffs did stop the flow of drugs across our borders with Mexico and Canada, you still have demand. So, you will get more black market products and higher priced drugs. You get it coming from elsewhere, or produced more in the United States. That's not the way to go about trying to deal with a fentanyl problem. It is a way to throw around your weight as a big country without achieving the underlying objective.

What I鈥檓 trying to say in this long answer is this鈥攊f you have five problems you want to address, using one tool, tariffs, will never get you there. Tariffs are indirect and a very rough, blunt instrument that doesn't generally get you what you want, and we'll find that out.

What is the impact on the regular consumer?

The share of consumption that low income households pay for tariffs is much, much higher than it is for middle income or higher wealthier consumers. We've done some estimation on the results of implementing Trump鈥檚 campaign promises on tariffs; promises that included a 20鈥25% across the board tariff on all imports and a 60% tariff on all goods coming from China.

Looking strictly at the consumption of imported goods, that policy would cost the average American household about $2,500 as an additional tax. And $2,500 imposed on a family of four with relatively low income, say $50,000, $60,000; that is a big chunk of their regular consumption possibilities. And it would cause real, real hardship.

What about the overall impact on the national economy?

Nobody in business really knows from week to week what the tariffs will look like, whether they鈥檙e in place, what the rates are, etc. You cannot establish an investment program that makes sense under those circumstances.

Also, higher prices and higher costs associated with tariffs will push the economy into slower growth. I think it's pretty clear that within the next 12 to 15 months, we'll be in a recession, partly associated with these tariffs.

Tariffs, since the 1950s, have rarely been an element of generating a recession, because they haven鈥檛 been that important to American costs. Now, with this uncertainty and this dramatic increase in the level of tariffs, I think things have fundamentally changed, and we will see, in my estimation, both rising unemployment and rising inflation, in what we call a 鈥渟tagflation.鈥

Is there anything people can do to prepare for economic changes or challenges caused by tariffs?

It will take some time for the tariffs to work their way through to higher prices. So if you are thinking about buying a car, now is the time to do it, especially a foreign car.

When people are feeling more uncertain about the future, they tend to consume less and save more. That's a perfectly rational decision because they need that kind of cushion. I would encourage people to think a little bit more about what kind of goods they really need to spend on in this time of uncertainty. Prices will go up on products subject to tariffs, so maybe you want to buy it now, but you also want to have some cushion.听

91传媒 Today regularly publishes Q&As with our faculty members weighing in on news topics through the lens of their scholarly expertise and research/creative work. The responses here reflect the knowledge and interpretations of the expert and should not be considered the university position on the issue. All publication content is subject to edits for clarity, brevity and听university style guidelines.